Drawing comparisons to a "moonshot" in health care is usually reserved for breakthroughs like curing cancer. But no less impactful would be legislation to adopt a health care price-disclosure policy that would empower consumers to better control their health care costs. With transparent prices, consumers would be able to compel competition over cost in the health care marketplace, simply by exercising the opportunity to make fact-based choices.
This mandatory disclosure policy, as proposed in legislation at the Minnesota Legislature, would not be a silver-bullet solution but the addition of a sorely missing tool to rein in soaring health care costs, which should be a bipartisan priority.
The late Uwe Reinhardt, recognized as one of the leading authorities in health care economics for more than four decades, was famous for answering the question about what drives high U.S. health care costs with the assertion: "It's the prices, stupid."
Reinhardt emphasized the importance of health care price transparency and suggested that an important factor "facilitating high U.S. prices for health care was the shroud of secrecy draped over the health prices negotiated in the private sector. Those prices were kept as trade secrets. Rare were the physicians, hospitals, imaging centers or other clinicians or health care centers who posted on their websites the prices for frequently performed procedures. Furthermore, few health care practitioners or centers were willing to quote prices over the phone for even standard procedures, such as a normal vaginal delivery."
The implication of Reinhardt's remarks was that if patients knew more about the costs of their care services, they and their physicians would make better decisions.
Reinhardt pointed out that price transparency exists in virtually every segment of the U.S. economy except health care. He would raise the question: Why are prices hidden from patients? Perhaps it is not possible to determine the true costs? Or perhaps health care organizations are reluctant, even embarrassed, to reveal the actual costs and price variability to patients, such as the wide disparities in prices from hospital to hospital.
For instance, how can a Caesarean delivery cost $1,100 in one hospital and $2,500 in a hospital across the street? The care might be better, but not $1,400 better. Why does the same device or drug cost two or three or even 10 times more in the United States than in Europe?
To bring down intractably rising health care costs, we have been told for years by employers and health insurance companies to be wise health care consumers. But how can we be wise consumers if we don't know the actual prices of health care services, products and procedures?