Opinion editor’s note: Strib Voices publishes a mix of national and local commentaries online and in print each day. To contribute, click here.
•••
“My plan is that no family, no working family, should pay more than 7% of their income in child care.” That’s what Vice President Kamala Harris said at a recent event in Philadelphia with the National Association of Black Journalists when asked about what she would do about the rising cost of child care. Compared with former President Donald Trump’s answer to a similar question a few weeks ago, in which he meandered from to tariffs to his daughter before declaring that “child care is child care,” it was at least a direct answer, if light on details.
Unfortunately, the one detail included in Harris’ response — the cap on costs at 7% of income — is problematic. It’s a worthy and necessary goal to have child care cost a smaller share of family income, but latching too tightly on to this number risks a Trojan horse of administrative burdens and implementation difficulties.
The idea of a 7% cap goes back to a Census Bureau report in 2013 that summarized child care arrangements in the U.S. Among its findings was that about 38% of children under the age of 5 had no regular child care arrangement, and 11% of children over 5 were often at home alone and unsupervised. Also, mothers with children under 15 who were employed but not self-employed (about 60% of mothers) who were also paying for some form of care (about 32% of those mothers) paid on average 8% of their monthly income for that care. That number had averaged 7% since 1997. Voila! The magic number was 7%!
A year after the census report, the Child Care and Development Block Grant (CCDBG) was reauthorized. Among its many purposes, CCDBG funds child care vouchers for very low-income families. The vouchers aren’t an entitlement, as many who qualify don’t receive them. States are also allowed to charge voucher users copayments. The 2014 CCDBG capped those copayments at 7% of monthly income, informed by the Census Bureau report. Since then, 7% of income has become the benchmark for child care affordability. It’s obviously aspirational. The 7% estimate described money spent on care of children up to age 15. Limited to spending for full-time care for children under 5 would be significantly higher; Care.com estimates it was around a quarter of income last year.
It’s not the percentage that’s problematic, but the idea of using a percentage of income. There are 18.5 million children under 5 in the U.S. Say the federal government decided tomorrow it would fund all child care less 7% of family income from each participant. How should families pay their 7%? One option would be to have the providers collect it. This is the worst path, as providers would now be in the business of tabulating and verifying income. And it would incentivize those providers to take on children from richer families, where the 7% is higher.
It would be much more efficient to eliminate that transaction entirely, with providers billing the state for care and the state collecting the 7% copayment on the backend. That’s got issues, too. Nine states don’t collect income taxes, and if reimbursement depended on state income, the care subsidization would grow as unequally as the states, where median income ranges from $52,000 in Mississippi to $96,000 in New Jersey. Best to eliminate that transaction as well. The state gets money based on the number of children, not their income, and the federal government collects the 7% copayment on the backend.