On April 2, the federal government announced that about 6.6 million people filed for unemployment benefits that week. The week earlier about 3 million Americans had filed. Until theses last two weeks, the worst week for unemployment filings was 695,000 in 1982.
And the economic pain is surely just starting. If current rates persist, upwards of 25% of the workforce soon could be unemployed, a number greater than was reached during the Great Depression of the 1930s.
But ignoring the coronavirus outbreak could lead to the death of millions of Americans. The pandemic forces us to make cruel choices among unhappy alternatives.
To see the kind of trade-offs we face, it is useful to think about the determinants of this epidemic. The number of people who will be infected over any period of time depends on the number who are currently infected and the rate at which infected people transmit the virus to susceptible people.
This transmission rate, in turn, is determined by biological factors — the chances an infected person will pass this particular virus to a susceptible person during a meeting — and by economic factors — the number of susceptible people an infected person meets and the conditions under which those meetings take place.
Public policy can do little about biological factors, but it can do a lot about the economic factors. One policy, which we think of as the current approach, is to limit meetings for almost everyone by imposing mass quarantines, ostensibly for a limited amount of time. At the end of the day, a "shelter in place" is simply a mass quarantine policy. And this policy will indeed reduce infections as long as it continues in place.
But this policy also has costs. A substantial fraction of economic activities require, or have enhanced value from, people being close to each other. To understand the value of social proximity, ask yourself a simple question: Why would people choose to pay the high rents of downtown Minneapolis (or the insanely high rents of midtown Manhattan), if not to be close to other people? Why would firms choose to pay the insanely high rents they pay to be in urban centers, if they did not value their employees being near each other?
Indeed, the last three decades have witnessed a rise in the market value of social proximity precisely at the time the internet was supposed to be freeing us from the usefulness of being near each other. Densely populated large cities have grown more rapidly in terms of economic output than sparsely populated rural areas.